To explore some effects of price competition, we begin by
considering a simple two-broker system with a single information
category. We assume that brokers and consumers are fully
knowledgeable about the state of the system (in particular,
they know the prices and interest vectors of all of the brokers).
Furthermore, they instantly adjust their desired
subscription vectors
and
to maximize their utility given
the current set of prices and interest vectors.
This last assumption removes the degrees of freedom
associated with the subscription matrix by expressing
it in terms of the other state parameters (prices and
interest vectors) -- a tremendous simplification.
We assume that the brokers update their prices asynchronously. One plausible strategy is for a broker to set its price to the value that maximizes its profit, assuming all other prices remain fixed. Such an update strategy is guaranteed to produce the optimal profit up until the moment when the next broker updates its parameters. We call such a strategy ``myopically optimal'', or myoptimal.
A useful construct for understanding the resulting dynamics
is the profit landscape. We define a broker's
profit landscape as its utility (given in Eq. 2)
as a function of the prices offered by all brokers in the system,
itself included. A contour map of the profit landscape for broker
1 in a system with , V=1, and a uniform distribution
of consumer interests is shown in Fig. 3a.
Figure 3: a) Contour map of profit landscape for broker 1
for , with overlaid optimal price function
.
Profit is higher in dark regions.
b) Graphical construction of price-war time series,
using functions
and
.
The landscape shown in Fig. 3a
has two distinct humps. The ``cheap'' hump on the right
corresponds to the case where broker 1 is
cheaper ( ). Here, its profit is completely independent
of
, and it can charge the monopolistic price derived previously.
The ``expensive'' hump on the left corresponds to the case
in which broker 1 is more expensive than
broker 2, but still able to find customers. This comes about
when broker 2 is charging so little that it cannot afford to
keep marginal customers -- i.e., customers with low interest levels
-- as subscribers. (Recall from the discussion
of the single-broker case that a broker will veto a subscription
from an insufficiently interested prospective customer.)
For these marginal
customers, the only alternative is to subscribe to broker 1.
In other words, broker 2's rejects constitute broker 1's market.
If broker 1 is myoptimal, it can derive from its profit
landscape a function that gives the
value of
that maximizes the profit when broker 2
charges price
. This function is represented as a heavy
solid line in Fig. 3a.
For
,
is given by the solution to a cubic equation
involving cube roots of square roots of
; in this region it looks
fairly linear. The ``vertical'' segment
at
is a discontinuity as the optimal price jumps
from the ``expensive'' hump to the ``cheap'' hump.
When
,
,
where
is a price quantum -- the minimal amount by which
one price can exceed another. For
,
,
the monopolistic price.
If broker 2 also uses a myoptimal strategy,
then by symmetry its landscape and price-setting
function are identical under an
interchange of
and
.
Then the evolution of both
and
can be obtained
simply by alternate application of the two price optimization
functions: broker 1 sets its price
,
then broker 2 sets its price
,
and so forth.
The time series may be traced graphically on a plot of both
and
together, as shown in
Fig. 3b.
Assume any initial price vector
, and suppose broker 1 is the first to move.
Then the graphical construction starts by
holding
constant while moving horizontally to the
curve for
. Then,
is held constant while moving
vertically to the curve
.
Alternate horizontal moves to
and
vertical moves to
always lead to a price war
during which the brokers
successively undercut each other, corresponding to
zig-zagging between the diagonal segments of the curves. Eventually,
the price gets driven down to 0.389, at which point
the undercut broker (say broker 1) opts out of the price war,
switching to the expensive hump in its profit
landscape by setting
. This
breaks the price war, but unfortunately
it triggers a new one. The brokers are
caught in a never-ending, disastrous limit cycle
of price wars punctuated by abrupt resets, during which
their time-averaged utility is half what they expected,
and less than half of the monopolistic value.